Unit of time and normalization of time preference rates












1












$begingroup$


Consider an infinite horizon cake eating differential game described by
begin{align}
&max_{u_1(t)} int_0^infty{e^{-r_1 t}ln(u_1(t))dt}\
&max_{u_2(t)} int_0^infty{e^{-r_2 t}ln(u_2(t))dt}\
text{s.t.} quad &dot x(t) = -u_1(t)-u_2(t)
end{align}

where $t in [0,infty)$ refers to the current time, $u_i(t)$ to the consumption rate of player $i in {1,2}$ and $x(t)$ to the size of the cake.



I'm interested in the time preference rates $r_i > 0$.
Without further explanations I found in Clemhout and Wan, 1989, On Games of cake-eating, p. 131




Since one can always choose a unit for time without losing generality, we suppose that the length of a unit of time is such that the preference rates of the two players sum up to unity.




That is, we can normalize $r_1 + r_2 = 1$.
But what does this mean actually? I'm particular puzzled about the without loss of generality part.










share|cite|improve this question









$endgroup$

















    1












    $begingroup$


    Consider an infinite horizon cake eating differential game described by
    begin{align}
    &max_{u_1(t)} int_0^infty{e^{-r_1 t}ln(u_1(t))dt}\
    &max_{u_2(t)} int_0^infty{e^{-r_2 t}ln(u_2(t))dt}\
    text{s.t.} quad &dot x(t) = -u_1(t)-u_2(t)
    end{align}

    where $t in [0,infty)$ refers to the current time, $u_i(t)$ to the consumption rate of player $i in {1,2}$ and $x(t)$ to the size of the cake.



    I'm interested in the time preference rates $r_i > 0$.
    Without further explanations I found in Clemhout and Wan, 1989, On Games of cake-eating, p. 131




    Since one can always choose a unit for time without losing generality, we suppose that the length of a unit of time is such that the preference rates of the two players sum up to unity.




    That is, we can normalize $r_1 + r_2 = 1$.
    But what does this mean actually? I'm particular puzzled about the without loss of generality part.










    share|cite|improve this question









    $endgroup$















      1












      1








      1





      $begingroup$


      Consider an infinite horizon cake eating differential game described by
      begin{align}
      &max_{u_1(t)} int_0^infty{e^{-r_1 t}ln(u_1(t))dt}\
      &max_{u_2(t)} int_0^infty{e^{-r_2 t}ln(u_2(t))dt}\
      text{s.t.} quad &dot x(t) = -u_1(t)-u_2(t)
      end{align}

      where $t in [0,infty)$ refers to the current time, $u_i(t)$ to the consumption rate of player $i in {1,2}$ and $x(t)$ to the size of the cake.



      I'm interested in the time preference rates $r_i > 0$.
      Without further explanations I found in Clemhout and Wan, 1989, On Games of cake-eating, p. 131




      Since one can always choose a unit for time without losing generality, we suppose that the length of a unit of time is such that the preference rates of the two players sum up to unity.




      That is, we can normalize $r_1 + r_2 = 1$.
      But what does this mean actually? I'm particular puzzled about the without loss of generality part.










      share|cite|improve this question









      $endgroup$




      Consider an infinite horizon cake eating differential game described by
      begin{align}
      &max_{u_1(t)} int_0^infty{e^{-r_1 t}ln(u_1(t))dt}\
      &max_{u_2(t)} int_0^infty{e^{-r_2 t}ln(u_2(t))dt}\
      text{s.t.} quad &dot x(t) = -u_1(t)-u_2(t)
      end{align}

      where $t in [0,infty)$ refers to the current time, $u_i(t)$ to the consumption rate of player $i in {1,2}$ and $x(t)$ to the size of the cake.



      I'm interested in the time preference rates $r_i > 0$.
      Without further explanations I found in Clemhout and Wan, 1989, On Games of cake-eating, p. 131




      Since one can always choose a unit for time without losing generality, we suppose that the length of a unit of time is such that the preference rates of the two players sum up to unity.




      That is, we can normalize $r_1 + r_2 = 1$.
      But what does this mean actually? I'm particular puzzled about the without loss of generality part.







      dynamical-systems optimal-control differential-games






      share|cite|improve this question













      share|cite|improve this question











      share|cite|improve this question




      share|cite|improve this question










      asked Dec 11 '18 at 23:45









      cluelessclueless

      298111




      298111






















          1 Answer
          1






          active

          oldest

          votes


















          0












          $begingroup$

          First note that $r_1>0$ and $r_2>0$. Let $r_i$ be such that $r_1+r_2=rho$. By introducing a new independent variable $tau=rho t$ we get
          $$max_{u_1(tau)} frac{1}{rho}int_0^infty{e^{-frac{r_1}{rho}tau}ln(u_1(tau))dtau}.$$
          The factor $frac{1}{rho}$ in front of the integral can be dropped as it doesn't influence the result. And the new discount rates $frac{r_i}{rho}$ now sum to 1.






          share|cite|improve this answer









          $endgroup$













            Your Answer





            StackExchange.ifUsing("editor", function () {
            return StackExchange.using("mathjaxEditing", function () {
            StackExchange.MarkdownEditor.creationCallbacks.add(function (editor, postfix) {
            StackExchange.mathjaxEditing.prepareWmdForMathJax(editor, postfix, [["$", "$"], ["\\(","\\)"]]);
            });
            });
            }, "mathjax-editing");

            StackExchange.ready(function() {
            var channelOptions = {
            tags: "".split(" "),
            id: "69"
            };
            initTagRenderer("".split(" "), "".split(" "), channelOptions);

            StackExchange.using("externalEditor", function() {
            // Have to fire editor after snippets, if snippets enabled
            if (StackExchange.settings.snippets.snippetsEnabled) {
            StackExchange.using("snippets", function() {
            createEditor();
            });
            }
            else {
            createEditor();
            }
            });

            function createEditor() {
            StackExchange.prepareEditor({
            heartbeatType: 'answer',
            autoActivateHeartbeat: false,
            convertImagesToLinks: true,
            noModals: true,
            showLowRepImageUploadWarning: true,
            reputationToPostImages: 10,
            bindNavPrevention: true,
            postfix: "",
            imageUploader: {
            brandingHtml: "Powered by u003ca class="icon-imgur-white" href="https://imgur.com/"u003eu003c/au003e",
            contentPolicyHtml: "User contributions licensed under u003ca href="https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-sa/3.0/"u003ecc by-sa 3.0 with attribution requiredu003c/au003e u003ca href="https://stackoverflow.com/legal/content-policy"u003e(content policy)u003c/au003e",
            allowUrls: true
            },
            noCode: true, onDemand: true,
            discardSelector: ".discard-answer"
            ,immediatelyShowMarkdownHelp:true
            });


            }
            });














            draft saved

            draft discarded


















            StackExchange.ready(
            function () {
            StackExchange.openid.initPostLogin('.new-post-login', 'https%3a%2f%2fmath.stackexchange.com%2fquestions%2f3036016%2funit-of-time-and-normalization-of-time-preference-rates%23new-answer', 'question_page');
            }
            );

            Post as a guest















            Required, but never shown

























            1 Answer
            1






            active

            oldest

            votes








            1 Answer
            1






            active

            oldest

            votes









            active

            oldest

            votes






            active

            oldest

            votes









            0












            $begingroup$

            First note that $r_1>0$ and $r_2>0$. Let $r_i$ be such that $r_1+r_2=rho$. By introducing a new independent variable $tau=rho t$ we get
            $$max_{u_1(tau)} frac{1}{rho}int_0^infty{e^{-frac{r_1}{rho}tau}ln(u_1(tau))dtau}.$$
            The factor $frac{1}{rho}$ in front of the integral can be dropped as it doesn't influence the result. And the new discount rates $frac{r_i}{rho}$ now sum to 1.






            share|cite|improve this answer









            $endgroup$


















              0












              $begingroup$

              First note that $r_1>0$ and $r_2>0$. Let $r_i$ be such that $r_1+r_2=rho$. By introducing a new independent variable $tau=rho t$ we get
              $$max_{u_1(tau)} frac{1}{rho}int_0^infty{e^{-frac{r_1}{rho}tau}ln(u_1(tau))dtau}.$$
              The factor $frac{1}{rho}$ in front of the integral can be dropped as it doesn't influence the result. And the new discount rates $frac{r_i}{rho}$ now sum to 1.






              share|cite|improve this answer









              $endgroup$
















                0












                0








                0





                $begingroup$

                First note that $r_1>0$ and $r_2>0$. Let $r_i$ be such that $r_1+r_2=rho$. By introducing a new independent variable $tau=rho t$ we get
                $$max_{u_1(tau)} frac{1}{rho}int_0^infty{e^{-frac{r_1}{rho}tau}ln(u_1(tau))dtau}.$$
                The factor $frac{1}{rho}$ in front of the integral can be dropped as it doesn't influence the result. And the new discount rates $frac{r_i}{rho}$ now sum to 1.






                share|cite|improve this answer









                $endgroup$



                First note that $r_1>0$ and $r_2>0$. Let $r_i$ be such that $r_1+r_2=rho$. By introducing a new independent variable $tau=rho t$ we get
                $$max_{u_1(tau)} frac{1}{rho}int_0^infty{e^{-frac{r_1}{rho}tau}ln(u_1(tau))dtau}.$$
                The factor $frac{1}{rho}$ in front of the integral can be dropped as it doesn't influence the result. And the new discount rates $frac{r_i}{rho}$ now sum to 1.







                share|cite|improve this answer












                share|cite|improve this answer



                share|cite|improve this answer










                answered Dec 14 '18 at 9:47









                DmitryDmitry

                671618




                671618






























                    draft saved

                    draft discarded




















































                    Thanks for contributing an answer to Mathematics Stack Exchange!


                    • Please be sure to answer the question. Provide details and share your research!

                    But avoid



                    • Asking for help, clarification, or responding to other answers.

                    • Making statements based on opinion; back them up with references or personal experience.


                    Use MathJax to format equations. MathJax reference.


                    To learn more, see our tips on writing great answers.




                    draft saved


                    draft discarded














                    StackExchange.ready(
                    function () {
                    StackExchange.openid.initPostLogin('.new-post-login', 'https%3a%2f%2fmath.stackexchange.com%2fquestions%2f3036016%2funit-of-time-and-normalization-of-time-preference-rates%23new-answer', 'question_page');
                    }
                    );

                    Post as a guest















                    Required, but never shown





















































                    Required, but never shown














                    Required, but never shown












                    Required, but never shown







                    Required, but never shown

































                    Required, but never shown














                    Required, but never shown












                    Required, but never shown







                    Required, but never shown







                    Popular posts from this blog

                    Probability when a professor distributes a quiz and homework assignment to a class of n students.

                    Aardman Animations

                    Are they similar matrix